Showing posts with label food prices. Show all posts
Showing posts with label food prices. Show all posts

Monday, January 16, 2012

Optimal food price stabilization in a small open developing country

In poor countries, most governments implement policies aiming to stabilize the prices of staple foods, which often include storage and trade measures insulating their domestic market from the world market. It is of crucial importance to understand the precise motivations and efficiency of those interventions, because they can have consequences worldwide. This paper addresses those issues by analyzing the case of a small, open developing country confronted by shocks to both the crop yield and foreign price. In this model, government interventions may be justified by the lack of an insurance market for food prices. Considering this market imperfection, the authors design optimal public interventions through trade and storage policies. They show that an optimal trade policy largely consists of subsidizing imports and taxing exports, which benefits consumers at the expense of producers. Import subsidies alleviate the non-negativity of food storage. In other words, when stocks are exhausted, subsidizing imports prevents domestic price spikes. 

One striking result: an optimal storage policy on its own is detrimental to consumers, since its stabilizing benefits leak into the world market and it raises the average domestic price. By contrast, an optimal combination of storage and trade policies results in a powerful stabilizing effect for domestic food prices.
 
In developing countries, staple foods frequently account for a significant share of poor households’budgets. Many poor people have limited possibilities to insure against adverse price shocks. Price spikes are very problematic for poor households that are not self-sufficient, and often jeopardize their capacity to feed themselves. An important response of developing country governments to expressions of this concern is to implement food price stabilization policies. Yet, the study of these policies has been confined mainly to closed economy contexts, with an emphasis on the role of storage (see Wright, 2001, for a survey). From a theoretical standpoint, little is known about the role of trade policy in price stabilization programs, despite their widespread use. Recourse to trade policy to counter price volatility has been common in most Asian countries where stabilizing the domestic price of rice is a central objective (Timmer, 1989, Islam and Thomas, 1996, Dorosh, 2008), and also in Middle East and African countries in the case of wheat and to a lesser extent maize as well as rice (Dorosh, 2009, Wright and Cafiero, 2011). The question is probably less acute in Latin America, where most countries are net exporters of grains, but it is not irrelevant, as witnessed by the use by Chile of a price-band system for wheat and a few other food products (Bagwell and Sykes, 2004). More generally, based on a large-scale database on agricultural price distortions, Anderson and Nelgen (2012) show that countries tend to vary their nominal rate of assistance to agriculture so as to limit the effects of variations in world prices on domestic prices.

Trade and trade policies are key aspects that need to be taken into account in considerations of food security and price stabilization in developing countries. They raise numerous questions, the most important perhaps being: How should storage and trade policies be combined to achieve price stabilization? Increased reliance on national buffer stocks is frequently suggested as a remedy for developing countries faced with significant volatility in world prices. But is this a consistent policy per se, independent of trade policy interventions? Dorosh (2008) suggests that greater reliance on the world market allowed much more cost-effective price stabilization in Bangladesh than in India; the latter relied almost exclusively on huge public stocks and severe restrictions on imports. Can it be taken for granted that greater trade openness, or more reactive trade policy, would reduce the amounts of stocks needed to achieve a given stabilization target, and to what extent?

Export restrictions raise a number of additional questions. Most analysts of the 2007–08 food crisis agree that trade policies played a significant role in fueling international price spikes (von Braun, 2008, Mitra and Josling, 2009, Headey, 2011). In particular, export bans enforced by several rice exporters seem to have contributed greatly to the astonishing price levels reached (Slayton, 2009). Noting the similar situation in the 1973–74 crisis, Martin and Anderson (2012) emphasize the collective action problem created by export restrictions: their use by some countries to provide shelter from price spikes aggravates the problem for others (see also Bouët and Laborde Debucquet, forthcoming). The restrictions imposed by Russia on its cereal exports following a drought in 2010 can only add to this concern. A first step towards coping with this problem is to achieve a better understanding of the motivations and consequences of export restrictions. Based on Marshallian surplus analysis, many authors conclude that such policies are harmful to the countries enacting them. Is this really the case, or do export restrictions make economic sense for a small open economy? And, in this case, is refraining from the imposition of export restrictions an important sacrifice for the country concerned? Would specific flanking policies be preferable?

World Bank.Author:Gouel, Christophe ; Jean, Sebastien.Document Date: 2012/01/01.Document Type: Policy Research Working Paper.Report Number: WPS594


Optimal food price stabilization in a small open developing country x

Thursday, December 8, 2011

Food prices almost unchanged



8 December 2011, Rome - The FAO Food Price Index in November was virtually unchanged from its October level. At the new level of 215 points, the Index was 23 points, or 10 percent, below its peak in February 2011 but remained two points, or one percent, above its level in November 2010.

The prices of cereals, one of the main commodity groups included in the
Food Price Index, dropped by 3 points or 1 percent from October. The retreat was largely driven by wheat prices, which dropped 3 percent, while rice quotations fell only slightly and coarse grain prices remained virtually unchanged. Nevertheless, the cereals index remained 6 points higher than in November 2010.

Contributing to the downward pressure on cereal prices is the significant upward revision of the 2011/2012 global cereal supply estimate as a result of better crop prospects in some Asian countries and the Russian Federation, and larger than anticipated stocks in the latter. Other factors include deteriorating world economic prospects and a strong U.S. Dollar.
Record level of total cereals
These are among the highlights of the latest issue of FAO's quarterly
Crop Prospects and Food Situation report published today. The report confirmed a record level of world cereal production of 2 323 million tonnes for 2011. Although marginally lower than October's estimate, this represents a 3.5 percent increase on 2010 production.

At this level, the 2011 cereal crop should be sufficient to cover the expected increase in utilization in 2011/12 and also allow for a moderate replenishment of world reserves, the report said.

Among cereals, global wheat output is expected to increase by 6.5 percent, while the forecasts for coarse grains and rice were reduced slightly due to a downward adjustment for maize in the United States and a deterioration of rice prospects in Indonesia.

Animal feed up, and also stocks

Total cereal utilization in 2011/2012 was forecast at 2 310 million tonnes, 1.8 percent higher than in 2010/2011. An important feature is a sharp, 8 percent rise in the use of wheat for animal feed given its competitive price compared to coarse grains and maize in particular.

The forecast for world cereal ending stocks by the close of seasons in 2012 has been raised by almost five million tonnes since last month, to 511 million tonnes, the report said. At this level world cereal stocks would be 10 million tonnes higher than last year and the world cereal stocks-to-use ratio would increase slightly to 22 percent.

Crop Prospects and Food Situation — which focuses on developments affecting the food situation of developing countries and in particular Low-Income Food-Deficit Countries (LIFDCs) — noted that given their likely increased import requirements, the aggregate cereal import bill of LIFDCs for the 2011/2012 marketing season would reach a record level of US$33 billion — up 3.4 percent from 2010/2011.

Food insecurity hotspots

Reviewing the world's food security hotspots, the report said that despite some improvements in the situation in Somalia due to substantial humanitarian assistance and favourable rains food insecurity is expected to remain critical in drought-affected areas until the harvest of short-season crops in early 2012.

While famine conditions are expected to persist in Middle Shabelle and refugee populations in Afgoye and Mogadishu, the areas of Bay, Bakool and Lower Shabelle were downgraded from Famine to Emergency on 18 November

In the Horn of Africa as a whole, food insecurity remained critical for some 18 million people in most drought-affected areas, including 4.6 million in Ethiopia, 4 million each in Somalia and the Sudan, 3.75 million in Kenya, 1.5 million in South Sudan and 180 000 in Djibouti are in need of emergency assistance.
Irregular rains and civil unrest undermine food security
In West Africa, in several countries of the Sahel including Burkina Faso, Chad, Mali, Mauritania and Niger agricultural production has been hit by irregular rains and significant pest infestations. This could lead to price rises and food insecurity.

In the Near East, prolonged civil unrest in Syria and Yemen has disrupted trade and humanitarian aid distribution, limiting access to food, especially for vulnerable households.

FAO's latest estimates indicate that 33 countries around the world are in need of external assistance as a result of crop failures, conflict or insecurity, natural disasters and high domestic food prices.
x